58414 stories
·
2 followers

The Demagogic Case for Open Borders

1 Share

Open Borders: The Science and Ethics of Immigration is my most persuasive book. Anyone who closely reads the book loses, on average, about half of their opposition to immigration. Yet sadly, the absolute number of readers remains low. As a graphic novel, it only takes two hours to read, but that’s still asking too much.

Almost no one wants to actually read anything; if I’m lucky, they’ll listen to me speak for five minutes. And with those attention constraints, I’ve learned time and again, I’m barely persuasive on immigration at all. Sharing five minutes of intellectually sound arguments sways almost no one.

Given all my writings on demagoguery, I shouldn’t be surprised. Successful politicians base their power on the charismatic delivery of pretty lies. As a conscientious scholar, I refuse to stoop to their level. But it does make me wonder: If I was willing to go full demagogue in defense of open borders, what would I say?

Probably something like what I’ve written below the flag. Dear readers, I give you… my demagogic case for open borders.

The United States is a country of immigrants. Some of us are the children of immigrants. Others their grandchildren or great-grandchildren. But the only reason any of us are here is that someone born elsewhere chose to move to this great country. And a big part of what made this country great is that when newcomers arrived, we welcomed them, we worked with them, and we had children together. American children.

Now I ask you, when this great country first welcomed your ancestors, was it a sacrifice? Was it charity? Were your parents, grandparents, and great-grandparents a burden on this country? Of course not. They showed up with big American dreams — and big American drive to make those dreams happen. It’s thanks to our courageous ancestors who forsook the Old World that we’re Americans today.

Every other country would have refused them. Only America had the vision and heart to look at our ancestors and extend the earnest hand of friendship. Instead of sneering, “They’re not good enough for us!” they saw fine people ready to work hard to make a better lives for their families. And they weren’t wrong. That’s just the way it happened. And because past generations of Americans had this vision and heart, we became the greatest country in the history of the world. E pluribus unum — “out of many, one.” America has always been a beacon of hope — and that’s why we’re the light of the world.

And that’s why it breaks my heart to hear my fellow Americans look at the latest generations of immigrants and say those awful words, “They’re not good enough for us!” We’re here because our ancestors knew better. Our ancestors knew that when someone arrives on our shores in ragged clothes, speaking broken English, carrying their half-starved kids, a real American is not fooled. He looks past the failures of the Old World and sees the latest family of Americans. People not looking for a hand-out, or even a hand-up, but just a warm handshake: “Welcome to America, land of opportunity.”

I’m an American, not an American’t. Name any complaint you’ve got about immigrants. I’ve heard them all. They’re the same complaints naysayers had about our ancestors. What do you think about the folks who said that your ancestors were “too different,” “too lazy,” “too stupid” to provide for their own families in this great country?

They weren’t just mean, and they weren’t just wrong — though they certainly were both. Worse, they were un-American. Because if you believe in this country, you don’t even need to listen to these crybabies. If you want to do the right thing, you’ll find a way. Otherwise, you’ll find an excuse.

European Immigrants Cheered Lady Liberty - Racing Nellie Bly

Being an American was never easy. It meant looking past the sins of the governments of the people we welcomed. Being an American meant welcoming Germans who grew up worshipping the Kaiser. Being an American meant welcoming Russians who grew up worshipping their Czar. Being an American meant welcoming the tribe that everyone else on Earth blamed for crucifying Jesus Christ himself.

And that’s why, when American faced its greatest challenge in World War II, we had millions of German-Americans, Russian-Americans, and Jewish Americans on our side. Fighting on the beaches. Planning in the war rooms. And engineering war-ending atomic bombs underneath the University of Chicago. If he’d lived in modern times, Jesus Christ wouldn’t have just given us the moral lessons this country was founded on. I firmly believe that he would have chosen to become a proud American citizen.

And that’s what we have to remember whenever someone says, “Immigrants are great, except.” Exceptions are not the American way. We’ve got to welcome the people of all nations. We’ve got to welcome them with the same confidence past generations of Americans welcomed our ancestors. There’s always a few bad apples, but the American solution is American justice for the individually guilty — and that’s all she wrote.

You can attack this country, but you’ll never kill the American dream. A dream that tells the whole world: No matter how bad things seem, there’s a special country out there ready to take a chance on you, if you’ll take a chance on her. A special country called the United States of America.

America is immigration, and immigration is America. It’s my story. It’s your story. And it’s the story that the whole world needs to hear. God bless America, and God bless every one on Earth who dreams of America. Because together, we’re going to make the greatest country on Earth greater than it’s ever been.

[End demagoguery.]

P.S. I know, of course, that the U.S. wasn’t history’s only open borders country!

Read the whole story
gangsterofboats
6 hours ago
reply
Share this story
Delete

Capitalism Fought Jim Crow From the Start

1 Share
I have long praised a happy result of the free market: It discourages racism. Two memorable examples I have brought up here include commercial desegregation in Houston (when segregation was called "bad for business") and the universal reach of the Sears catalog across the South.

Both of these show capitalism blunting the force of segregation, or helping end it outright.

Notably, thanks to a recent John Stossel article, we can now add a historic example of capitalism actively resisting Jim Crow due to the power of self-interest:
Image by Unknown Photographer, via Wikimedia Commons, public domain.
"It's often forgotten that owners of buses, railways, streetcars in the American South didn't really segregate systematically until the late 19th century," says [economist Johan] Norberg [, author of Capitalist Manifesto]. "It was probably not because they were less racist than others in the South, but they were capitalists. They wanted money, they wanted clients, and they didn't want to engage in some sort of costly and brutal policing business in segregating buses."

Even when segregation was mandated, some streetcar companies refused to comply. For several years after Jim Crow laws passed, black customers sat wherever they wanted.

Norberg adds, "Those owners of public transport, they fought those discriminatory laws because they imposed a terrible cost….They tried to bypass them secretly and fight them in courts. They were often fined. Some were threatened with imprisonment."

The streetcar company in Mobile, Alabama, only obeyed Jim Crow laws after their conductors began to get arrested and fined. [bold added]
Notice that capitalism, the system that respects individual rights, strongly penalizes racism, because it is antithetical to a person's actual self-interest: It took the active abuse of government, in the form of fines and imprisonment, to fully implement the costly folly of treating customers badly, or forfeiting them altogether.

I have not myself read Norberg's book, but on this evidence, it appears to be worth consideration by any serious advocate of capitalism or racial equality.

-- CAV
Read the whole story
gangsterofboats
7 hours ago
reply
Share this story
Delete

Hamas Celebrates Proposed Ceasefire With Rocket Barrage

1 Share

GAZA — With reports of a proposed agreement to temporarily end hostilities in the conflict between Israel and Palestine, Hamas celebrated the proposed ceasefire with a rocket barrage directed toward Tel Aviv.

Read the whole story
gangsterofboats
7 hours ago
reply
Share this story
Delete

Vaccination has averted 154M deaths

1 Share
Comments
Read the whole story
gangsterofboats
15 hours ago
reply
Share this story
Delete

Milton Friedman vs Ayn Rand: How to Change the World

1 Share


https://youtu.be/Bg9BFE1-49Y




Podcast audio:







In this episode of New Ideal Live, Onkar Ghate and Nikos Sotirakopoulos discuss Milton Friedman’s impact as a public intellectual and how his advocacy of the free market differed from Ayn Rand’s radical philosophical case for capitalism.



Among the topics covered:




* Why Milton Friedman is an essentially positive influence on free market thought;



* How Friedman’s moral conventionality reinforced the ideas he tried to oppose;



* The importance of stating the ideal when advocating for gradual reform;



* Why questions of morality are at the root of economic issues;



* How Friedman’s amoralism and pragmatism blinded him to the statists’ motivation;



* Ayn Rand’s critical evaluation of Friedman;



* Why the abolitionist movement is a model for moving the world toward freedom.




Mentioned in this podcast is Onkar Ghate and Yaron Brook’s course “Cultural Movements: Creating Change” and Ayn Rand’s essay “Tax Credits for Education.”



The podcast was recorded on May 2, 2024. Listen and subscribe from your mobile device on Apple PodcastsGoogle Podcasts, Spotify or Stitcher. Watch archived podcasts here.






Download video: https://www.youtube.com/embed/Bg9BFE1-49Y



Download audio: https://media.blubrry.com/new_ideal_ari/content.blubrry.com/new_ideal_ari/20240502_Milton-Friedman-vs-Ayn-Rand.mp3
Read the whole story
gangsterofboats
15 hours ago
reply
Share this story
Delete

The Fairytale of Hegemonic Neoliberalism

1 Share


One of the great untold stories of the 20th century political left is how they lost the debate on economic issues within the economics profession. So they moved over into the English department (and other humanities) instead, and resumed teaching discredited economics there. This might explain, explains Phil Magness in this guest post, why many of the humanities adopt an explicitly conspiracist epistemology when they talk about economics as a discipline — and why their graduates adopt an explicitly conspiracist approach to opposing political ideas. As examples, you can see the recent "scare" over the Atlas Network, and the long-running scare story about how the world is being taken over by something called "neoliberalism."

What is "neoliberalism"? As Magness explains, "neoliberalism" is essentially an intentionally imprecise stand-in term for free-market economics or for economic sciences in general; for conservatism, or for libertarians and anarchists; for authoritarianism and for militarism; for advocates of the practice of commodification, for centre-left or market-oriented progressivism; for globalism and for welfare-state social democracies, for being in favour of or against increased immigration; for celebrating rocketing house prices or promoting policies to make them fall; for favouring trade and globalisation or opposing the same; or for really any set of political beliefs that happen to be disliked by the person(s) using the term. In short, it's a fairy-tale used to describe any kind if "dragon" a certain type of person is against. But dragons don't exist.

The Fairytale of Hegemonic Neoliberalism

by Phil Magness

Nobel laureate economist Joseph Stiglitz recently made waves in academic circles with a book declaring the end of something called “neoliberalism” and outlining the contours of a suitable replacement.

“That question has come to define the current era,” Stiglitz explained. After describing the allegedly dying paradigm with a series of vague economic concepts that include tax cuts, deregulation, and global finance, he declared “the neoliberal experiment” a “spectacular failure.”

His prognostication received a celebratory response from political commentators, many of whom have similarly proclaimed the concept’s demise in anticipation of a more progressive replacement paradigm. Obituaries of this type are now a weekly feature of political and academic commentary. Stiglitz himself also previously announced the “death” of neoliberalism several times to similar fanfare in 2019, in 2016 — and in 2008 before that.

Curiously, among all the cries that the neoliberalism wolf is dead or dying, little attention has been given to a more fundamental question: Does that wolf even exist? And did it ever exist?

Origins


I’ve examined the origins of the term “neoliberalism” before, tracing it back to 1920s Germany, when it served as a favourite term of disparagement for laissez-faire economics used by Marxists and fascists alike. So clearly it has an earlier use. But pejorative terminology originating in discredited extremist ideologies from interwar Germany is a grossly deficient basis on which to establish that the maligned object is anything other than a caricature.

“Neoliberalism” has certainly become a favoured academic buzzword used since that time, although common notice of it in the scholarly literature dates no earlier than the mid-1980s, when attention was drawn to it by the French philosopher Michel Foucault. Even then the term did not achieve widespread academic use until the late 1990s [popularised here in EnZed by the likes of Jane Kelsey], and it has only supplanted another favourite bugbear of the activist world, “globalisation,” in the last decade or so — globalisation having having now become a scare-word for the other side of the political spectrum!

Still, this usage pattern remains exceedingly strange for an ideological paradigm that is commonly alleged to have dominated  economic policy right up to the present day. Conventional depictions of “neoliberalism” routinely assert that this paradigm captured the economic policy-making apparatus of the United States, and eventually the world, starting around 50 to 70 years ago. The dating alone necessarily entails that the alleged neoliberal takeover took place before the vast majority of the world even knew that neoliberalism existed, let alone what neoliberalism was. Which poses an obvious question ...

Where Have All the Neoliberals Gone?


When one probes this strange usage pattern a little further, it quickly becomes apparent that the term’s anachronistic deployment is only the beginning of its problems as a suitable descriptor. The term’s very definition is, to put it mildly, fluid and notoriously imprecise. As Jason Brennan and I note in our book Cracks in the Ivory Tower, neoliberalism is essentially an intentionally imprecise stand-in term for
free market economics, for economic sciences in general, for conservatism, for libertarians and anarchists, for authoritarianism and militarism, for advocates of the practice of commodification, for center-left or market-oriented progressivism, for globalism and welfare state social democracies, for being in favour of or against increased immigration, for favouring trade and globalisation or opposing the same, or for really any set of political beliefs that happen to be disliked by the person(s) using the term.
The “neoliberal” designation has been applied to an array of political and economic beliefs, including internally contradictory ones. In the political-candidate space, it purports to describe everything from Hillary Clinton to Donald Trump. To those who use it with regularity, the only recurring certainty is that neoliberalism is bad. Or to quote left-wing columnist George Monbiot, neoliberalism is “the ideology at the root of all our problems.”

Except there’s also another problem beyond the term’s fluid definition. When investigating the seemingly obvious question of who actually espouses neoliberalism, one quickly finds that almost nobody actually subscribes to this supposedly dominant paradigm. There are almost no actual people who call themselves “neoliberal” — who advocate, adopt, or seek to impose “neoliberalism” on the economy. Nor have there ever been.

Some readers might respond that the term was batted about between the 1938 Walter Lippmann Colloquium and the mid-’50s as a way to rebrand classical liberalism. This is nominally correct. But the adoption of this name was contested from the outset in 1938, and never really stuck on the free market or laissez-faire side of that internal debate, its supposed home in both the interwar German uses and in the academic discussion between 1990 and today.

At best, the self-described “neoliberals” of the midcentury drifted into an attempted melding of (1) international free market liberalism in matters of trade, regulation, and commerce with (2) a robust and fiscally solvent European-style welfare state. Not only does this latter half of this equation meet with approval on the progressive left, but it’s a much more difficult case to maintain that the modern American economy is a derivative of the eventual product of that midcentury discussion, the German Ordoliberal school.

There are also a handful of recent attempts by free market thinkers to re-appropriate the “neoliberalism” label for themselves. But this movement is entirely a response to the term becoming academically trendy in the past decade, not any intellectual continuum to a laissez-faire past. Commendable as the effort to change the word’s overwhelmingly pejorative use into a positive may be, its current adherents probably number in the hundreds. They both postdate the claimed “neoliberal” takeover and remain far removed from the instruments of power that it supposedly wields — and has wielded for over 50 years.

So practically speaking, the total number of people in the world today who would identify themselves with the allegedly dominant ideology of the last half-century is negligible. In fact, the number of academics on the left who devote their lives to decrying “neoliberalism’s” supposed stranglehold over the American and global economies exponentially exceeds the total number of self-described adherents of neoliberal ideology today or at any time in the past.

Taking Neoliberalism Seriously


Neoliberalism, we are constantly told, still runs the show, has run the show for over half a century, and is on the verge of being replaced by a progressive alternative on account of its “failures.” So what happens then if we take this cliché at face value? What happens if we try to actually identify where and how specific neoliberals came to control American economic policy after World War II?

The term’s modern use has exceptionally strong association with Ludwig von Mises — one of the economists who rebuffed the moniker at the aforementioned 1938 colloquium — and with Milton Friedman, who preferred to call himself a classical liberal. As much as we may value their respective economic contributions, neither Mises nor Friedman ever enjoyed anywhere close to the widespread control over economic policy that is often ascribed to them.

Both wrote in an age when Keynesianism was ascendant in economics, and particularly when Keynes’s American expositor Paul Samuelson enjoyed nearly complete saturation in economic education due to the popularity of his college textbook and associated political prescriptions.

Mises articulated a sweeping case against economic interventionism on both philosophical and practical grounds, including a recurring observation that central planning was both inherently susceptible to graft and impossible to implement without disastrous misallocation. Briefly stated, the entire premise of the central planner undercuts the signaling mechanism of prices, which in turn renders him incapable of allocating goods and services to functionally meet even basic consumer wants and needs. Yet Mises remained an outsider to the halls of political influence until his death in 1973, and only found wider vindication after the fall of the Soviet Union validated his longstanding critique of their economic model. [SEE: 'Mises Against the Neoliberals']

Friedman is a somewhat similar case in that his best-known policy work, Capitalism and Freedom (1962), was an outsider’s critique of the entire New Deal order and subsequent welfare state. His monetary theories did acquire some policy salience in the 1970s, but only after stagflation revealed systemic faults in the dominant Samuelsonian approach to central banking that had taken hold in the previous two decades.

While Friedman’s brand of monetarism is frequently credited in the “neoliberalism” literature for the aggressive interest rate “shock” policies of Paul Volcker at the Federal Reserve (1979-87) in a quest to tame inflation, this common account conveniently neglects that Friedman himself was harshly critical of the Fed throughout the same period that it was supposedly under his philosophical guidance. Near the end of the Volcker term, Friedman went so far as to denounce the Fed’s record as an erratic and politically manipulated succession of missteps that openly rejected a stable monetarist rule even while speaking in nominally monetarist rhetoric.

Note that even here one can still legitimately debate the extent to which a Friedmanite policy undergirded these events, but the record points to a messy implementation at best and one that forced him into confrontation with the blunderous obstacles of political execution. It did not, however, entail a “neoliberal” takeover of even monetary policy either before or since that moment, let alone the entire economic paradigm.

Neoliberalism and Political Influence


Far from signifying its validity, Mises and Friedman are actually illustrative of a central defect in the “neoliberalism” literature. Their prescriptive approaches to economic policy — typically calling for a deeply constrained or rule-based form of economic intervention in Friedman’s case, and broad adherence to economic non-intervention in Mises’s framing — have been eschewed for politically entrenched alternatives that favour proactive government intrusions into most economic matters.

Even more so, the main political instruments of economic policy making reveal a conspicuous absence of supposedly “neoliberal” figures throughout this period.

As my friend Peter Boettke recently remarked, there was never a Treasury Department operating under the guidance of James M. Buchanan; never a Friedman Fed; never a Hayekian Council of Economic Advisors.

Instead, the more common norm for political appointments to key economic positions is (1) traditional Keynesians, (2) liberal and conservative New Keynesians, and (3) technocratic empiricists of both the center-left and progressive variety. Instead of “neoliberals,” we find these roles populated in the more progressive moments by Samuelson, or Robert Solow, or James Tobin, or Walter Heller, or Arthur Okun, or Alan Krueger, or — yes — Joseph Stiglitz (chair of the CEA, 1995-97) himself. In more conservative moments such as the George W. Bush administration, key economic policy appointments have typically gone to New Keynesians such as Ben Bernanke and Gregory Mankiw.

One could extend this observation to international bodies that allegedly represent the “neoliberal” era as well.

Although some recent works have attempted to write Mises and Friedrich Hayek into the deep genealogy of the World Trade Organization, the World Bank, the IMF, and similar institutions, the evidence for such paths of influence resembles more of a “six degrees from Kevin Bacon” game than any meaningful shaping of policy.

Key “neoliberals,” at least of the Misesian free market non-interventionist type, are always noticeably missing from the formative political events of these institutions, such as the Bretton Woods conference of 1944 (attended by Keynes himself, along with an assortment of New Dealers) and the key rounds of the General Agreement on Trade and Tariffs (1948) that eventually produced the WTO in 1995. [SEE ALSO: 'Why Austrians are Not Neoliberals']

And when one looks to the modern political leadership of these allegedly “neoliberal” institutions, they do not find laissez-faire theorists or Friedmanites or Hayekians or Misesians. Instead, one is more likely to find their leadership roles populated by political and economic figures hailing from the left of centre and favouring varying degrees of interventionist technocracy. These institutions routinely attract career politicians such as Dominique Strauss-Kahn and Pascal Lamy, left-of-center New Keynesians such as Lawrence Summers, or — once again — progressives such as Joseph Stiglitz (World Bank chief economist, 1997-2000) himself.

Given these and other recurring patterns of political appointments that chafe with the notion of a politically dominant “neoliberalism” paradigm, it becomes entirely reasonable to question the utility of the entire “neoliberalism” literature. Far from fighting to supplant a prevailing ideology for our age, “neoliberalism’s” critics appear to be battling a phantasm of their own imagining.

And conveniently, that phantasm also serves as an intellectually unsophisticated and pejoratively deployed stand-in for any and all things the same people dislike about free market economics without having to actually engage free-market arguments.

* * * * * 

Phillip Magness is an economic historian specialising in the 19th century United States. He is the author of numerous works on the political and economic dimensions of slavery, the history of taxation, and the history of economic thought. 
Dr Magness spent over a decade teaching public policy, economics, and international trade at institutions including American University, George Mason University, and Berry College. His work has appeared in scholarly outlets including the Journal of Political Economy, the Economic Journal, Economic Inquiry, and the Journal of Business Ethics. In addition to his scholarship, Magness’s popular writings have appeared in numerous venues including the Wall Street Journal, the New York Times, Newsweek, Politico, Reason, National Review, and the Chronicle of Higher Education.
His post first appeared at the American Institute of Economic Research.


Read the whole story
gangsterofboats
15 hours ago
reply
Share this story
Delete
Next Page of Stories